Post-war displacement of Keynesianism

The Post-war displacement of Keynesianism was a series of events which from mostly unobserved beginnings in the late 1940s, had by the early 1980s led to the replacement of Keynesian economics as the leading theoretical influence on economic life in the developed world. Similarly, the allied discipline known as Development economics was largely displaced as the guiding influence on economic policies adopted by developing nations.

The displacement of Keynesian thinking was driven by those who leaned towards purer free market policies rather than the mixed economy which require a significant role for government intervention. Their motivations included a dislike of large governments which they saw as prone to interfere excessively in the lives of their citizens; an intellectual preference for Classical or Neoclassical economics and related schools; or in some cases a belief that their individual interests were best served by promoting a limited role for government. Efforts against Keynesianism took place on three fronts – in the academic world, in politics, and in the wider world of business and public opinion.

Contents

Background

Starting in 1936 with the publication of his General Theory, the Keynesian revolution in economic thinking had by the end of the 1940s elevated John Maynard Keynes's ideas to an ascendant position in main stream economics. During the Golden Age of Capitalism of the 1950s and 1960s, governments of the United States , Great Britain and many other countries adopted Keynesian principles, where moderate government intervention was believed by Keynesians to deliver higher levels of employment and prosperity than would be possible from the unaided free market.

In the academic sphere, Keynes position as the principal authority was largely confined to the Anglo Saxon world - elsewhere Keynes was influential but not as central. This is partly as neo classical economics,[1] the system of thought which Keynes launched his revolution against, had never been as established beyond the English speaking nations in the first place - instead there was often a tradition of using mixed economy models such as the French dirigiste system.[2] While a critic of Keynes, the economic journalist Henry Hazlitt was to write in 1959:[3]

Keynes has conquered the present Anglo-American academic world, and the present Western political world, almost as completely as Marx has conquered Russia and China.

Similarly, the economic policies adopted in the developing world were largely based on Development economics – although that branch of economics is usually regarded as distinct from Keynesianism,[4] it is also a mixed economy model with many of its principles based on Keynes's work.[5] In the early years after WWII the US was highly supportive of development economics as they believed it would help accelerate the roll back of imperialism, inhibit the spread of communism and swiftly help under developed nations to become prosperous capitalist economies; so they heavily funded its promotion by United Nations programs.[5] The only significant parts of the world that had rejected Keynesian principles was the communist nations which used the command economy model.

In the 1960s forces emerged that by the mid 80s would end the accendency of Keyne's ideas. For Keynes's biographer Lord Skidelsky these can be divided into practical and intellectual dimensions; they are inter-related but in a complex and indirect way.[6] The failure of what were at the time perceived to be Keynesian economics to halt the stagflation of the 1970s lent credibility both to academic and popular attacks on Keyne’s ideas. Some even argued that the poor economic performance were due to Keynesian economics. The latter view has been roundly rejected by post keynesians, who suggest the inflation following the Vietnam war was due to the decision not to pay for the war with tax rises, against Keynesian advice.[6][7][8]

Economic historians have labelled the period from about 1951 - 1973 as the Age of Keynes or more commonly the Golden Age of Capitalism due to its relatively high average global growth, low unemployment, reduction of inequality, lowering of public debt and very low incidence of financial crises. After the transition period of the 1970s, the period that spanned from about 1980 - 2009 has been labelled the Washington consensus era.[6]

Think tanks and the counter Keynesian revolution in academic economics

As early as 1947, Friedrich von Hayek had gathered together some 40 intellectuals with free market sympathies to form the Mont Pelerin Society. They were mostly economists but also included journalists , historians and philosophers. Their explicit intention was to nurture intellectual currents that would one day displace Keynesianism and other collectivist influences. Prominent members included Karl Popper, Austrian School founder Ludwig von Mises along with the then young Milton Friedman. Initially the society had little impact on the wider world - Hayek was to say it was as if Keynes had been raised to sainthood after his death with economists refusing to allow his work to be questioned.[9][10] Yet in the decades following its establishment the Mont Pelerin Society came to take a central role within a network of over 100 pro free market think tanks located all over the world.[11] The think tanks typically enjoyed financial support from commercial interests. Collectively the think tanks won increased acceptance for free market thinking within accademia, within public opinion and among governments. In the US two of the most influential free market think tanks were the Foundation for Economic Education and the Heritage Foundation. In the UK perhaps the two most influential were the Institute of Economic Affairs and the Adam Smith Institute.[12]

Hayek himself dropped out of mainstream economics in 1950 to work chiefly in political philosophy.[5] Friedman and other allies continued to work as economists, though initially they only had marginal influence on the discipline as a whole.[5]

According to Professor Keith Shaw an important early milestone in Friedman's campaign against Keynesianism was the 1956 publication of Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money. [13] In this work Friedman restated the Quantity theory of money , and obtained the attention of several Keynesian economists partly because he admitted Keynes was right to state the velocity of circulation of money in the Equation of exchange can vary, rather than being a contrast as assumed by classical economists. However, Friedman's restatement was otherwise closer to the classical view in reducing the scope for beneficial government intervention in the economy.[13] An even more influential work was his 1963 publication of A Monetary History of the United States. Drawing on extensive empirical data, it further strengthened the case for his restated Quantity theory of Money, arguing that inflation was "always and everywhere a monetary phenomena", while conceding it could take one or two years for an increase in the money supply to lead to inflation. This ran counter to the then orthodox Keynesian interpretation that inflation was linked to employment, as modelled by the Phillips curve which predicted an inverse relationship between the two variables. Governments at the time would use the Phillips curve as part of their models to calculate the expected cost in terms of inflation for a stimulus designed to restore full employment. In 1968 Milton Friedman published a paper arguing that the fixed relationship implied by the Philips curve did not exist , and that it would be possible to have both inflation and unemployment rise at once.[14][15] Friedman had also argued that workers expectations of future high inflation could lead to an inflationary spiral as they would push for increased wages in advance to try to compensate for expected future inflation.

Friedman's work began to gain increasing acceptance among academics after 1973, when stagflation - the simultaneous increase in both inflation and unemployment - became prominent, just as he had predicted. While the 1973 oil crisis was clearly an inflationary shock to the global economy, Friedman was able to argue persuasively that inflation was much higher that it would have been due to the rapid expansion of the money supply by governments in 1971. By the lates 1970s , empirical data was also present to suggest Friedman was right to emphasise the role of expectations on inflation, further increasing the acceptance of his ideas by main stream economists.[5] Post Keynesian economist Paul Davidson has argued that part of the reason for Friedmans intellectual vicitory was that Keynes's ideas were misunderstood by the main stream academics of the time ( the Neo-Keynesians ) who therefore didn't have a consistent framework to rebut the attacks.[8]

So prominent was Friedman and other Monetarist economists in overturning the Keynesian consensus that the efforts to do so are sometimes referred to as "Milton Friedman's counter revolution." However there were several other key influences. Professor Roger E Backhouse lists the Lucas critique which led to the increasing influence of Rational Expectations and Real Business Cycle Theory ;[5] Professor Gordon Fletcher identifies the same influences as Backhouse while also adding S H Frankel's attack which was based on the work of Georg Simmel along with the influence of the Austrian School and especially Hayek, who enjoyed a resurgence in the 1970s; [16] Journalist Adam Curtis describes how game theory and other ideas arising from the cold war provided additional support for the theories Hayek had articulated in the forties, and helped them gain wider acceptance.[17]

These attacks were so successful that by 1980 Robert Lucas was saying economists would often take offence if described as Keynesians.[18]

The ascendancy of financial interests in the real world economy

When the Bretton Woods regime was established in the 1940s, free roaming international capitalists were "caged" to protect the economic interests of ordinary working people.[19] Capital controls were installed in all major countries. In Great Britain for example, at one point families were not allowed to take more than £50 abroad for their foreign holidays.[20] Even before the controls were put in place, international transactions were at historically low levels, as financiers and speculators had been weakened or at least made wary by the long depression of the 1930s and the war.[21]

Nevertheless, power slowly began to shift back from public to private interests. The 1970s were a key decade for this process, but Financial innovation had begun to erode the effectiveness of capital controls as early as the late fifties, an example being the Eurodollar market which the US authorities decided not to regulate.[22]

Elliot and Atkinson state 1968 was a pivotal year when power shifted in the favour of private agents such as currency speculators. They pick out a key 1968 event as being when America suspended the conversion of the dollar into gold except on request of foreign governments, which they identify as when the Bretton Woods system Keynes had helped to architect first began to break down.[19] Further key events were the Nixon Shock of 1971 when conversion to gold was suspended even for governments, the collapse of the fixed exchange rate system in 1973, and the United states official abandonment of capital controls in 1974.[20] [23]

A common popular view was that the rise of financial power resulted from unplanned trends towards globalisation and technical innovation.[24][25] This view has been challenged by scholars such as Eric Helleiner, Louis Pauly and Susan Strange, who argue that the US and British administrations encouraged financial liberalization even as early as the late 1950s, when mainstream economics was still largely of the opinion that such a policy would be incompatible with the general welfare. Reasons given include a calculation by the US that with the erosion of the hugely favorable trade balance they had enjoyed for the first few years after the war, financial liberation would be a good peaceful way of promoting continued US hegemony as US banks were far more advanced than their competitors in the rival economies of Europe and Japan. Another reason given is that the Financial sector stood to gain hugely from financial liberalization and so vigorously lobbied government to allow it. Whereas the negative impact would be dispersed among all other sectors, with no one sector suffering greatly. So without a champion such as Keynes to stand up for the common good, a classic collective action problem prevented meaningful counter lobbying from occurring.[25][26]

Changes in public opinion

For most of the first two decades after World War II there was considerable enthusiasm among the public for Keynesian policy, which was seen as a way to avoid the economic chaos of the great depression. In Great Britain for example, the post war election was fought largely on the grounds of the two main party's conflicting economic policies. Clement Attlee's Labour party espoused Keynesian policies, while Churchill's Conservative party drew considerable inspiration from Hayek and his then recently published The Road to Serfdom. The public's desire for Keynesian policy has been widely credited for the landside victory won by Attlee, despite voter's great esteem for Churchill.[12] The public was generally in favour of government's efforts to enforce tight controls on private capital as public opinion was strongly against private speculators and financiers. Journalists Larry Elliott and Dan Atkinson say that it is hard for us today to imagine how dimly they were viewed.[19] The disparaging label Gnomes of Zürich were typical of how they were described during this period.[19]

Various events began to erode the public's faith in the goodness of government, gathering force from the mid-fifties. For Britain and her dominions a key event was the 1956 Suez Crisis along with strands of thought in both the counterculture such as the work of R.D. Laing and in mainstream academia such as the thinking of Isaiah Berlin who to varying degrees were cynical of the establishment's claims to want the best for folk, arguing that their true motivation was to advance their private interests or simply the thrill of exerting control.[17] In the United States, Ayn Rand's popular novel Atlas Shrugged helped generate public enthusiasm for a return to laissez-faire capitalism - opinion polls have ranked her work as being the second most influential book on Americans after the Holy Bible.[27][28]

Concerns over the true motivations of public officials were further encouraged by Public choice theory. A rudimentary form of this theory was promoted from the early 1960s by James Buchanan, at the expense of Keynes's standing both in public opinion and among academics.[17][29] Journalists Elliot and Atkinson write that by the late sixties the younger generation had grown up with no experience of life before the managed economy, and therefore had no reason to be grateful to it. Instead they were skeptical about the establishment's pretensions of altruism, in some cases hostile to what was perceived as its materialism and in other cases passionate for much more progressive causes.[19] A notable worldwide eruption of these feelings was the Protests of 1968. In the US, disenchantment at the Vietnam War and what was seen as the failure of Keynesian responses[30] against inflation further contributed to the public's loss of faith in government.[8] Buchanan and James Wanger's 1977 book Democracy in Deficit: the Political Legacy of Lord Keynes was one of the more effective attacks against remaining pro-Keynes opinion.[6] A follow up book The Consequences of Mr Keynes (1978) by Buchanan and John Burton, further attacked Keynes for his alleged naivete in believing politicians and bureaucrats are largely motivated by benevolence.[29] This is not to say the public as a whole became positive about the free market, in the seventies those advocating its principles would still sometimes be pelted with eggs and flour bombs by hostile student audiences. However public opinion in the English speaking world was slowly won over. By the eighties free market institutions were once again widely respected if not widely admired, despite the occasional popular work that tried to bring their dark sides to the public's attention, such as Oliver Stone's film Wall Street and Tom Wolfe's novel The Bonfire of the Vanities.[31]

Changes in government policy

For the Anglo-American economies, Keynesian economics typically was not officially rejected until the late 1970s or early 1980s. Formal rejection was generally preceded by several years by the adoption of monetarist policies aiming to reduce inflation, which tended to counteract any expansionary fiscal policies that continued to be employed until Keynesianism was formally discarded.[32] In Britain Keynesian economics was officially rejected by Margaret Thatcher's new government in 1979, ending the Post-war consensus. There had been initially unsuccessful attempts to establish free market favouring policies as early as 1970 by the government of Edward Heath. In 1976 the then Prime Minister James Callaghan stated that "spending our way out of recession" is no longer an option. According to Skidelsky, Callaghan's statement is widely seen as marking the end of the Keynesian age.[6] In the US it was Reaganomics that fully displaced Keynesianism in 1981, again this had been preceded by a significant movement in the direction of monetarism by President Jimmy Carter's 1979 appointment of Paul Volcker as Chairman of the Federal Reserve. In Australia and New Zealand the era of Keynesianism was ended by the election victories of prime ministers Bob Hawke (1983) and Roger Douglas (1984) respectively , though in both cases Keynesian economics had already fallen partly out of favour.[33] In Canada the transition was less clearly marked, though Pierre Trudeau had begun to adopt monetarist anti inflationary measures from as early as 1975. [34] Likewise on continental Europe the transition away from Keynesian economics was less distinct, partly as Keynes had not been as important there, as European states had generally pursued Dirigiste measures even before Keynes, never having embraced classical economics in the first place.[2][35]

In South American efforts were made to displace development economics as early as the mid fifties, by Milton Friedman's Chicago School with some government support, as it appeared there was a risk that the developmentalist policies could encourage socialism .[36] However despite success in setting up franchises in Latin American universities and educating passionate individual free market economists, the efforts had little political effect. However later events such as the 1973 coup by Augusto Pinochet in Chile brought in governments who strongly favoured free market policies. In other Latin American countries pivotal individual events are much harder to pin down, but a gradual process described by author Duncan Green as a "silent revolution" had largely displaced development economics with free market influences by the mid 1980s [37]

In the developing countries of Africa and Asia the mid seventies saw a backlash against the trend towards liberalism by the west, with a group of some 77 developing nations making determined efforts to lobby for a revived Bretton Woods system with strengthened capital controls to protect against adverse movements of private finance.[38] But again commitment to development economics largely faded away and by the mid 1980s the free market agenda was broadly accepted.[23] Exceptions were countries large enough to retain independence and continue to employ mixed economy policies, such as India and China. China employed a command economy model throughout the 1950s and 60s; Economic reforms in China began in 1978 taking them closer to a mixed economy model, though one based more on pragmatic principles rather than specifically on Lord Keynes's ideas. India persisted with heavily interventionist policies until the early 1990s, when she began to liberalise after her 1991 crisis, though still retaining aspects of the mixed economy model such as extensive use of capital controls.

See also

External links

Notes and references

  1. ^ Keynes more commonly used the term classical economics in his attacks, but is widely accepted (e.g., Hayes ,2008, Eward Elgar publishing, The Economics of Keynes ISBN 978-1-84844-056-2 p 2) that he generally meant what we would now call neo classical economics
  2. ^ a b Roy Hattersley (2009-09-05). "Keynes: Two studies of his economic theories". The Guardian. http://www.guardian.co.uk/books/2009/sep/05/keynes-roy-hattersley-review. Retrieved 2009-09-08. 
  3. ^ Henry Hazlitt. "The Failure of the New Economics - complete book on PDF" (PDF). Ludwig von Mises Institute. http://mises.org/books/failureofneweconomics.pdf. Retrieved 2009-09-08. 
  4. ^ For very undeveloped countries its been argued (e.g. by Subrata Ghutah, 2003, Routledge Introduction to development economics p39 - 43) that the economy behaves closer to the classical model than to Keynes's - as output tends to be very inelastic there is no multiplier effect from stimulus , and due to said elasticity along with money dualism (many much preferring land or commodies like gold to the legal tender, especially when they wish to save) increases in the money supply tend to translate to price rises in the classical fashion as predicted by the Quantity theory of money.
  5. ^ a b c d e f Backhouse, Roger (2002). The Penguin History of Economics. Penguin. pp. 236, 294–297,. ISBN 0140260420. 
  6. ^ a b c d e Robert Skidelsky (2009). Keynes: The return of the Master. Allen Lane. pp. 101, 102, 107–117. ISBN 9781846142581. 
  7. ^ Though while war efforts were being escalated, the extent of war spending was hidden from President Johnson's Keynesian Economic Council, see The return to Keynes (2010) , p29
  8. ^ a b c Paul Davidson (2009). The Keynes Solution: The Path to Global Economic Prosperity. Palgrave Macmillan. pp. 1–3 , 161–169 , 175–177. ISBN 978-0230619203. 
  9. ^ Daniel Yergin and Joseph Stanislaw. "transcript of Commanding Heights documentary, episode 1". PBS. http://www.pbs.org/wgbh/commandingheights/shared/minitextlo/tr_show01.html#6. Retrieved 2009-07-03. 
  10. ^ Friedrich Hayek. "interview: Friedrich Hayek on John Maynard Keynes - Part II". hayekcenter. http://hayekcenter.org/?p=849. Retrieved 2009-07-03. 
  11. ^ A few of the free market think tanks pre-dated even the Mont Pelerin Society, most of them were founded in the 70s or later.
  12. ^ a b Cockett,, Richard (1995). Thinking the unthinkable: think-tanks and the economic counter-revolution, 1931-1983. Fontana Press. ISBN 0-00-637586-3. 
  13. ^ a b Shaw, Keith (1988). Keynesian Economics: The Permanent Revolution. Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd. pp. 52–56,. 
  14. ^ Friedman, Milton (March 1968). "The Role of Monetary Policy". American Economic Review,. 
  15. ^ Friedman had earlier made similar arguments verbally in his 1967 speech to the American Economic Association, where he had also first proposed his theory of the Natural rate of unemployment
  16. ^ Fletcher, Gordon (1989). The Keynesian Revolution and Its Critics: Issues of Theory and Policy for the Monetary Production Economy. Palgrave MacMillan. pp. xix - xxi. 
  17. ^ a b c Adam Curtis (2007). The Trap part 1, see also parts 2 & 3 (TV documentary). UK: BBC and google video. http://video.google.co.uk/videoplay?docid=404227395387111085&ei=eTSmStvJMpHo-QbRs7zrBA&q=the+trap+part+1&hl=en#. 
  18. ^ Alan Blinder (June 2001). "Keeping the Keynesian Faith". Princeton University. http://www.princeton.edu/~blinder/papers/01WE.pdf. Retrieved 2009-06-27. 
  19. ^ a b c d e Larry Elliott , Dan Atkinson (2008). The Gods That Failed: How Blind Faith in Markets Has Cost Us Our Future. The Bodley Head Ltd. pp. 6–15, 72–81. ISBN 1847920306. 
  20. ^ a b Wolf, Martin (2009). Fixing Global Finance. Yale University Press. pp. xi. 
  21. ^ Orlin, Crabbe (1996). International Financial Markets (3rd ed.). Prentice Hall. pp. 2–12. ISBN 0132069881. 
  22. ^ Daniel R. Kane (Mar 1982). The Eurodollar market and the years of crisis. Croom Helm and Google books. ISBN 9780709915225. http://books.google.com/?id=v7wNAAAAQAAJ&pg=PA85&lpg=PA85&dq=The+Eurodollar+market+and+the+years+of+crisis&q=. Retrieved 2009-09-07. 
  23. ^ a b James M. Boughton. "Silent Revolution: The International Monetary Fund 1979–1989". International Monetary Fund. http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/history/2001/index.htm. Retrieved 2009-09-07. 
  24. ^ Walter B. Wriston (1988). "Technology and Sovereignty". Foreign Affairs. http://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/43987/walter-b-wriston/technology-and-sovereignty. Retrieved 2010-12-27. 
  25. ^ a b Helleiner,, Eric (1995). "Introduction". States and the Reemergence of Global Finance: From Bretton Woods to the 1990s. Cornell University Press. ISBN 0801483336. 
  26. ^ In edition to Helleiner (1995) and the numerous sources he cites, see Great Transformations (2002) by Mark Blyth for more on how the US government was persuaded to support financial liberalisation. For a useful video documentary covering this topic, especially with relation to Britain but also the US see Adam Curtis's The Mayfair Set - Curtis covers additional aspects such as the increased power markets gained after they were flooded with oil money following the 1973 price rise; and how in the 1960s the British government initially tolerated emergent phenomena such as Corporate raiding as a possible solution to industrial inefficiency.
  27. ^ Though others have rated the book joint second in influence with To Kill a Mockingbird.
  28. ^ Mark Shousen (2007-03-06). "'Atlas Shrugged' – 50 years later". Christian Science Monitor. http://www.csmonitor.com/2007/0306/p09s01-coop.html. Retrieved 2011-07-08. 
  29. ^ a b Wayne Parsons (2002). "Keynes and his crtics". The Cambridge history of twentieth-century political thought. Cambridge University Press. pp. 65–66. ISBN 1859844294. 
  30. ^ In his 2009 book The Keynes Solution Paul Davidson argues that the failing responses were not really Keynesian at all, but based on a misunderstanding of Keyne's ideas.
  31. ^ Thompson, Graham (2006). American culture in the 1980s. Edinburgh University Press. ISBN 0748619100. 
  32. ^ Cornwall, John (1990). The Theory of Economic Breakdown: An Institutional-Analytical Approach. Blackwell Pub. ISBN 0631148817. 
  33. ^ Goldfinch, Shaun (2000). Remaking New Zealand and Australian Economic Policy. Georgetown University Press. ISBN 0878408460. 
  34. ^ Finkel, Alvin (2006). Social policy and practice in Canada: a history. Wilfrid Laurier University Press. p. 286. ISBN 0889204756. 
  35. ^ Heilbroner, Robert (2000). The Worldly Philosophers. pp. 278–8. 
  36. ^ Klein, Naomi (2007). The Shock Doctrine. Penguine. pp. 50–78. 
  37. ^ Green, Duncan (2003). Silent Revolution: The Rise and Crisis of Market Economics in Latin America. New York University Press. ISBN 1583670912. 
  38. ^ Krasner, Stephen (2003). Structural Conflict: The third world against global liberalism. University of California Press. ISBN 0520054784.